Picture taken from DAWN's website |
One reason for which Asad had been
criticised during his tenure was for taking too long in striking a deal with
the IMF. The argument goes that markets do not like uncertainty. Higher policy
uncertainty forces firms to delay their investment decisions thus depressing
growth. Moreover, expecting depreciation, individuals may convert their savings
to dollars. Likewise, exporters may temporarily park their foreign currency
earnings overseas.
While these arguments have obvious merits, the
core thesis ignores the other side of the story. Specifically, it ignores the
cost of entering an early IMF program. This is mostly done out of convenience.
It is much harder to predict how the economy would have turned out had we made
different decisions in the past.
Before proceeding further, let us get an
important point of confusion out of the way. There is not much you can
negotiate when you are seemingly negotiating with the IMF. A favourable deal is
easier to achieve through using your international relations rather than forwarding
competing economic arguments.
It is also important to appreciate where
the country stood at the time when Asad took charge. First, the consumption led
growth model had once again brought the country at the verge of a balance of
payment crisis. At 5.7 percent of GDP, current account deficit was almost three
times bigger than in FY13. Second, foreign currency reserves had depleted in
the process of financing the import bill and defending the overvalued exchange
rate. Third, the build-up of circular debt due to factors including unfunded
subsidies required a Rs3.82 per unit increase in price of electricity as
proposed by NEPRA. Fourth, a new phenomenon of circular debt in the gas sector
had emerged after the outgoing government dragged her feet on increasing gas
prices during preceding years. At one point, OGRA had proposed a 300 percent increase in gas prices for domestic consumers. Fifth, the budget presented by
the outgoing government pushed a significant proportion of salaried class out
of the tax net. Sixth, the collection of advance tax during previous fiscal year
to artificially shore up revenue collection, blocked refunds and Supreme
Court’s ruling against tax on mobile cards further depleted revenue sources. In
short, everything was in a mess!
Considering these challenges, the question
was never about what steps had to be taken. The economy had to be slowed down
to contain imports; exchange rate could no longer be defended; electricity
prices had to go up to contain circular debt; gas prices had to increase to
prevent the supply-chain in the gas sector from collapsing; the tax base had to
be restored; the process of refund had to start to resolve financing problems
of exporters; finally, tax exemptions and unfunded subsidies had to be
withdrawn.
Instead, the only relevant question was how
and when. The economic managers under Asad had to decide if they would do this
at once or gradually in phases. To their bad luck, the IMF came down hard demanding
a rather immediate adjustment across all these dimensions. Commentators at the
time were of the view that the government may be better off entering an IMF
program at once. The argument went that the new government should expose the
economy they had inherited; enter an IMF program; and, start with a clean slate.
The argument had its merits. But, perhaps, most
commentators did not fully appreciate the implication of what they were proposing:
a front-loaded adjustment program. Imagine if the government would have entered
an IMF program right after coming to power. What would have happened? First,
exchange rate would have been left to free float. As a result, exchange
devaluation would have been much steeper and much bigger. Second, electricity
prices would have increased by close to Rs3.8 per unit. Third, average gas
prices would have more than doubled. Fourth, tax exemptions would have been
withdrawn and new taxes would have been imposed.
All this would have led to a much higher rate of inflation and, consequently, a much higher interest rate. The growth rate, as a result, would have been much lower than the 3.3 percent achieved during fiscal year 2019. Perhaps, in our counterfactual world, the commentators would have been criticising the government at an even higher pitch.
All this would have led to a much higher rate of inflation and, consequently, a much higher interest rate. The growth rate, as a result, would have been much lower than the 3.3 percent achieved during fiscal year 2019. Perhaps, in our counterfactual world, the commentators would have been criticising the government at an even higher pitch.
Instead, Asad’s economic team continued to
‘negotiate’ with the IMF while
undertaking gradual adjustment. Despite some mismanagement, exchange rate was
allowed to adjust in several steps. Electricity prices were increased by
one-third of the recommended amount. Likewise, gas prices were increased by an
average of 35 percent. This was contrary to the initial proposal of increasing
gas prices by three times the actual increase. The tax concessions were partially reversed. A
mechanism was designed to start the process of refunds. The interest rate was
increased but by less than what the IMF wanted.
These steps did increase inflation and
slowed down economic growth. However, by delaying the IMF program, Asad and his
economic team effectively spread the adjustment process over a longer period
than what the IMF would have allowed. Now that almost half of the adjustment
has already been made, a similar IMF program will be less painful as the
magnitude of required adjustments will be less than it would have been.
Yes, there were episodes of economic
mismanagement during this time. Yes, the economic climate is not going to get
better any sooner. However, the pain would have been much greater had Asad
conceded to a front-loaded IMF program right after taking charge.
------------------------------------------------------
Ahmed Jamal Pirzada has PhD in Economics. He teaches at the University of
Bristol and is also a visiting fellow at the SDPI. He
tweets at @ajpirzada
Bilal Lakhani is a Fulbright Scholar and alum of Columbia
University’s Graduate School of Journalism. He tweets at @MBilalLakhani